Good news everyone, health insurance doesn’t work

The passage of the AHCA through the House and the subsequent BCRA written in the Senate has made society at large anxious about the implications of these bills for the health of working Americans. Much of this fear has been fanned by politicians claiming that the bills will kill Americans. Bernie started off the parade:

Then Hillary jumped in:

Elizabeth Warren then accused the GOP of criminal activity:

These cuts are blood money. People will die. Let’s be very clear. Senate Republicans are paying for tax cuts for the wealthy with American lives.

— Elizabeth Warren

And then Nancy Pelosi gave an estimate of how bad the damage will be:

We do know that many more people, hundreds of thousands of people, will die if this bill passes

-Nancy Pelosi

If I was the average citizen, I would be terrified at this point. Fortunately, I’ve been trained to think like an engineer and I don’t get scared until the data tells me that I should be scared. There are several observational reports out there demonstrating that health insurance improves outcomes, some showing no effect, and some even showing that health insurance kills people overall. This is the problem with observational studies; they are especially vulnerable to vulnerable to selection bias and confounding and therefore are inconclusive and unreliable evidence. What we really want is experiments. Fortunately, there have been two major randomized controlled trials (aka real science) of the impact of health insurance coverage on health outcomes and mortality, the RAND health insurance experiment and the Oregon Medicaid experiment. What does the data tell us then? Good news everyone, you have nothing to worry about, because health insurance doesn’t do a damn thing.

The RAND Health Insurance Experiment is a gold standard study that ran between 1978 and 1983 on a sample of 3958 people by providing participants with health insurance with a randomized level of cost sharing ranging from 0% to 95% coinsurance . At the end of the experiment, the researchers concluded that:

For the average participant, as well as for subgroups differing in income and initial health status, no significant effects were detected on eight other measures of health status and health habits. Confidence intervals for these eight measures were sufficiently narrow to rule out all but a minimal influence, favorable or adverse, of free care for the average participant.

The Oregon Medicaid Experiment was the second randomized controlled trial, conducted between 2008 and 2010. In the study state of Oregon expanded Medicaid coverage to a random selection of 6387 beneficiaries out of a total of 12,229 eligible applicants, with the non-recipients being used as the control group. In the words of the researchers:

We found no significant effect of Medicaid coverage on the prevalence or diagnosis of hypertension or high cholesterol levels or on the use of medication for these conditions. Medicaid coverage significantly increased the probability of a diagnosis of diabetes and the use of diabetes medication, but we observed no significant effect on average glycated hemoglobin levels or on the percentage of participants with levels of 6.5% or higher. Medicaid coverage decreased the probability of a positive screening for depression , increased the use of many preventive services, and nearly eliminated catastrophic out-of-pocket medical expenditures.

Two major studies decades apart and they find the exact same thing: increased healthcare utilization, increased total healthcare spending (important finding: prevention doesn’t save money), increased financial security (and the corresponding mental health benefits), but no statistically significant effect on health status (they don’t teach you this part in school). The health insurance didn’t do anything to improve people’s health compared to those who didn’t receive insurance. Keep in mind that these are large studies involving thousands of subjects. They’re also not ‘partisan’ or biased. The Oregon study in particular was run by Finkelstein and Gruber, who worked on the ACA and would’ve loved to show a positive effect on health, they just couldn’t find one.

This is a surprising finding for most people. It’s pretty simple to establish a plausible relationship between health insurance and mortality. Person gets sick, person can’t get treatment, person dies. How can there be no positive impact of health insurance on mortality? There’s several reasons that are not immediately intuitive but are real scenarios. Consider the following:

Case 1. Man gets cancer. Man has health insurance. Man’s cancer has no treatment. Man dies. Health insurance had no effect on health.

Case 2. Man has a bad diet and doesn’t get exercise. Man gets diabetes. Man has health insurance. Doctor tells him what he needs to do. Man continues to eat poorly and not exercise. Man dies. Health insurance had no effect on health.

Case 3. Man gets cancer. Man has no health insurance. Man’s cancer has a treatment. Man partners with a charitable organization and gets his treatment paid for. Man lives. Health insurance had no effect on health.

Case 4. Man has a non-life threatening lesion on a scan. Man has health insurance, so the doctor orders a biopsy to check. Man acquires an infection during the biopsy and dies. He would’ve lived if he had no insurance and didn’t get the biopsy. Health insurance killed the man.

It must be noted how common these situations are. 1 in 25 hospital patients acquire an infection. 1 in 500 hospital patients get killed by a medical error. Medical errors are the 3rd leading cause of death in America. Let that sink in, your average internist is involved in involuntary manslaughter 1-2 times per month. On top of that the expensive stuff that kills people, we’re not even that good at treating it. Overall cancer survival is only 50-60%. We also don’t have the slightest clue on what to really do with heart disease, respiratory disease, diabetes and such, because we don’t know how to stop patients from being themselves. Raj Chetty’s megastudy from last spring (1.4 million individuals observed) showed that the biggest predictors of life expectancy wasn’t income but whether you drank, smoked and exercised. 9 out of the 10 leading causes of death in the U.S. are preventable by changing your behavior. The inconvenient truth is that no amount of health insurance is going to save a smoker from themselves, because you’re just throwing money into a fire. Health care simply does not work for people who don’t care about their health.

The sum of all this is that health insurance has some real cost/benefit tradeoffs, but none of them are to improve health or save lives, and politicians should be more careful about saying things that are scientifically untrue. If you want to save lives, then try prohibition (that went well the first time), because health insurance expansion doesn’t get you there.

(Obviously this is all in the context of marginal effects at US insurance coverage levels, your mileage may vary in other contexts)

Advertisements

NY’s Alternative Price Transparency

I recently attended a panel discussion about the future of healthcare reform and specifically the American Health Care Act that the Republicans unveiled (review coming up soon). When I asked the panelists about the importance of price transparency for the effective functioning of a free market, I was told that New York State passed a law requiring the top providers in the state to post prices for their procedures. This surprised me because I had never heard of this law, what great news!

A quick search of “New York price transparency law” reveals several unrelated articles about price transparency in general, a few links about a new pharmaceutical price transparency effort being pushed and then finally a link to New York Senate Bill S77 which seeks to “enact the transparency in health care fees act”. That sounds great so far, what does this thing do?

  S 2999-L. HEALTH CARE BILLS.  1. FOR PURPOSES OF  THIS  TITL  "HEALTH
CARE  PROVIDER"  SHALL  MEAN  A  PRACTITIONER IN AN INDIVIDUAL PRACTICE,
GROUP PRACTICE, PARTNERSHIP, PROFESSIONAL CORPORATION OR  OTHER  AUTHOR-
IZED  FORM  OF  ASSOCIATION, A HOSPITAL OR OTHER HEALTH CARE INSTITUTION
ISSUED AN OPERATING CERTIFICATE PURSUANT TO THIS CHAPTER OR  THE  MENTAL
HYGIENE  LAW,  A  CERTIFIED  HOME  HEALTH AGENCY OR A LICENSED HOME CARE
SERVICES AGENCY, AND ANY OTHER PURVEYOR  OF  HEALTH  OR  HEALTH  RELATED
ITEMS  OR SERVICES INCLUDING BUT NOT LIMITED TO A CLINICAL LABORATORY, A
PHYSIOLOGICAL LABORATORY, A PHARMACY, A PURVEYOR  OF  X-RAY  OR  IMAGING
SERVICES,  A PURVEYOR OF PHYSICAL THERAPY SERVICES, A PURVEYOR OF HEALTH
OR HEALTH RELATED SUPPLIES, APPLIANCES OR  EQUIPMENT,  OR  AN  AMBULANCE
SERVICE.
  2.  PRIOR  TO  PERFORMING  ANY  HEALTH  CARE SERVICES, ALL HEALTH CARE
PROVIDERS SHALL ADVISE PATIENTS IN WRITING OF THE FEE TO BE  CHARGED  TO
THE PATIENT FOR THE SERVICES TO BE RENDERED IN THE EVENT SUCH FEE IS NOT
PAID FOR BY INSURANCE.
  S 3. This act shall take effect immediately.

Beautiful! This is exactly the bill that our healthcare system needs. When does this go live?

Capture

Oh…it hasn’t passed into law yet, it’s still a proposal. That must be why I never heard of this bill. But it’s in the health committee, so that’s good news, right? It’s a good cost control mechanism that also has the benefit of protecting consumers from surprise billing, surely it will pass, right?

 LEGISLATIVE HISTORY :

S.344 of 2015-2016 (Hoylman): Died in Health
A.250 of 2015-2016 (Rozic): Died in Health
S.7124 of 2014 (Hoylman): Died in Health
A.3518 of 2013-2014 (Rozic): Died in Health

Of course it won’t pass. This is yet another incarnation of a bill that gets brought up every year (thank you state senators Hoylman and Rozic), gets sent to the health committee, and dies there. Well, I wonder why it keeps dying there? It’s most likely not so different from what happened to the price transparency law that was passed in Ohio:

The hubris of the healthcare lobby, as displayed by its actions after the law passed unanimously in June, 2015, is unfortunately telling.  The lobbyists who are ostensibly representing Ohio providers failed to even inform their members that this legislation passed, leaving the vast majority in the dark and unprepared to comply with the law.  This failure to inform provider members of legislation that would affect their practices is not surprising given the confidence of the lobby in its ability to reverse the will of the people.  According to the healthcare lobby, it “had the votes” (meaning had enough “friends” in the legislature) to repeal the law.

So if we don’t get to have true price transparency, as I was misinformed by the panelist, what do we have instead? In 2015 New York State passed a bill establishing FAIR Health as a benchmark pricing tool to protect consumers. FAIR Health claims that law offered “comprehensive healthcare cost transparency”, which is a very loose definition of comprehensive, since it does no such thing. What FAIR Health does do is provide an award winning consumer website that tells me that in my area my estimated out of pocket cost for a hemodialysis procedure with one physician evaluation is $85.50…

Capture

… which means absolutely nothing! What theoretical provider matches this estimate? What theoretical plan matches this coverage setup? What if the provider is out of my network? Of course they don’t even provide a recommendation of a provider that most matches this estimate.  And as a consumer that magical word “estimate” is really unsettling, because if I walk into the wrong facility, that cost could easily be much higher. So do I feel like I am protected from surprise fees? Am I able to shop around for a hemodialysis at the price best for me? Absolutely not, because we don’t have “comprehensive price transparency,” we have alternative price transparency.

And as long as we allow lobbies to hijack the legislative process to protect entrenched monopolies, that’s the price transparency we deserve.

Review: Rand Paul’s Obamacare Replacement Act

January 2017 is Obamacare hunting season and Sen. Rand Paul decided to throw his replacement plan proposal into the mix of Republican ideas on the discussion table. Finally we have something concrete and serious from the Republicans to work with. The summary can be found here and law nerds can find the entire 149 page bill on Capitol Hill here. So how does it look? Well, it’s not great. It’s actually pretty bad for a variety of reasons rooted in poor understanding of economics and human behavior, but let’s go over the summary section by section.

Repealing Obamacare

  • Effective as of the date of enactment of this bill, the following provisions of Obamacare are repealed: Individual and employer mandates, community rating restrictions, rate review, essential health benefits requirement, medical loss ratio, and other insurance mandates.

Alright, repealing the individual mandate is an immediate reprieve for the 6.5 million poor taxpayers whom the government was forcing to pay $3.0 billion in penalties because they valued having money for things like food and rent more highly than subsidized health insurance. Repealing the employer mandate is a benefit more broadly to the working class by making it easier for employers to hire above the 50 person boundary imposed by Obamacare. Repealing the insurance regulations and requirements allows them to revisit their plans and deliver a greater diversity of products that better match consumers needs. We’re doing well so far, let’s see what’s next.

Protecting Individuals with Pre-Existing Conditions

  • Provides a two-year open-enrollment period under which individuals with pre-existing conditions can obtain coverage.
  • Restores HIPAA pre-existing conditions protections. Prior to Obamacare, HIPAA guaranteed those within the group market could obtain continuous health coverage regardless of preexisting conditions.

Another good change. The patient protection portions of the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act were popular for obvious reasons, but they’re also the reason why it should be called the Patient Protection and Unaffordable Insurance Act. The Obamacare regulations give far too much protection to individuals and open up the insurance market to abuse by patients who take advantage of their information asymmetry by signing up for insurance only when they anticipate heavy usage of the healthcare system. Rolling back the regulations to the 1996  HIPAA pre-existing condition rules restores to insurance companies ways to protect themselves from such manipulation. These are good changes so far, but unfortunately this is the repeal portion of the bill. The rest is the replace portion, and it’s all downhill from here.

Equalize the Tax Treatment of Health Insurance

  •  Individuals who receive health insurance through an employer are able to exclude the premium amount from their taxable income. However, this subsidy is unavailable for those that do not receive their insurance through an employer but instead shop for insurance on the individual market.
  • Equalizes the tax treatment of the purchase of health insurance for individuals and employers. By providing a universal deduction on both income and payroll taxes regardless of how an individual obtains their health insurance, Americans will be empowered to purchase insurance independent of employment. Furthermore, this provision does not interfere with employer provided coverage for Americans who prefer those plans.

This is very bad economics. For those not familiar with this issue, there is a massive loophole in the tax code where health insurance benefits provided by the employer are not subject to taxation. The rule is rooted in World War II wage controls where employers were not allowed by the government to give employees salary increases because of the war effort, but the worker unions negotiated to be allowed to receive health insurance benefits instead of additional wages. Except the tax code did not have any provisions for these health insurance benefits. By the time that Congress realized this loophole, the unions had also realized that  they were effectively receiving a subsidy from the government on every dollar that they got paid in health insurance as opposed to wages, and the practice became so widespread that politicians were not able to muster the courage to go through with the fix. The result is that 60% of Americans receive insurance through their employer. This is an enormous economic problem, because it completely distorts the insurance market. The employer does not know your preferences, willingness to pay, and healthcare needs. Therefore making the employer  the primary purchaser of health insurance guarantees sub-optimal insurance selection and decreases market competition. If your employer provides only one or two insurance plan choices, did you as a consumer really participate in the insurance marketplace? By tying the insurance to the employer rather than the individual, it makes insurance less portable and forces the individual to renegotiate their insurance every time that they get a new job or move between state which makes people less likely to do so if they do develop a condition. In addition, the tax loophole results in an effective market distortion of the pricing signals (if they existed, more on that later) that the economy creates. By giving health insurance an effective 20-30% subsidy, this guarantees that people will purchase more insurance than they need and that providers, knowing that there is an excess of insurance protection in the marketplace, increase their prices in order to take advantage of this fact. This doesn’t make healthcare easier to pay for the insured, and makes it MORE difficult to afford for the uninsured. Expanding this loophole to insurance premiums for the sake of “equality” only makes the problem worse!

Expansion of Health Savings Accounts

  • Provides individuals the option of a tax credit of up to $5,000 per taxpayer for contributions to an HSA. If an individual chooses not to accept the tax credit or contributes in excess of $5,000, those contributions are still tax-preferred.
  • Removes the maximum allowable annual contribution, so that individuals may make unlimited contributions to an HSA.
  • Eliminates the requirement that a participant in an HSA be enrolled in a high deductible health care plan. Currently, in order to be eligible to establish and use an HSA, an individual must be enrolled in a high-deductible health plan. This section removes the HSA plan type requirement to allow individuals with all types of insurance to establish and use an HSA.

In addition to the above changes, there is a very long list of HSA deregulation giving people more freedom in how they can spend their HSA accounts and how they can transfer that money between people and funds if necessary. This is the core of the new Republican healthcare agenda, trying to move people off unlimited premium driven insurance plans and to a more cash based healthcare market. It’s a great idea, but it’s necessary to be critical and skeptical about this bill’s implementation. Critical because these changes further expand the tax loophole described above to cash based purchases of healthcare, which further inflates healthcare prices. This hurts the uninsured more than everybody else, because the insured are loss protected after their deductible limit is reached. It’s also necessary to be skeptical, because promoting health savings accounts implies that people are able to take their cash and use it to make purchases in a transparent competitive free market. No such thing exists.You can’t go to your local hospital’s website, navigate to the orthopedics section, and find out the cost of a hip replacement. Healthcare is the only industry where there are no publicly available prices and it’s acceptable to quote a price after the service has been delivered. Imagine airlines billed you for a transcontinental flight AFTER you arrived at your destination. Would you be surprised if they tried to overcharge you? Without transparent prices it’s completely irrational for consumers to try purchasing their healthcare on a cash basis. It’s safer to stick with your insurance than risk it with the HSA. Providers, for their part, will never be the first to provide prices because doing so would mean that they would have to actually compete for business and innovate, instead of generating profits by overcharging your insurance behind the scenes. Despite all the changes proposed by Sen. Rand, HSA’s in this bill are a non-starter without provider side reforms.

Charity Care and Bad Debt Deduction for Physicians

  • Amends the Internal Revenue Code to allow a physician a tax deduction equal to the amount such physician would otherwise charge for charity medical care or uncompensated care due to bad debt. This deduction is limited to 10% of a physician’s gross income for the taxable year.

Is this real? Somebody pinch me. Besides the obvious critique that this is a physician senator peddling to the physician special interest, here’s why this is a terrible idea. In Brazil health expenditure is a limitless tax deduction. So what do people do? They go to their friendly neighborhood physician and have him write out receipts for a large amount of fake healthcare which they use to reduce their taxable income while giving the physician a kickback for his cooperation in the scheme. Every single physician will max out this Sen. Paul tax deduction. Physicians  who did not have enough uncompensated care during the year will go to their friendly neighborhood uninsured patients to “provide” charity care until they reach 10% of gross income. In addition, this rule encourages physicians to increases the cost of their services, because Increasing their billing to insured patients increases their gross income, which in turn increases the allowed net amount of the 10% tax deduction.

Pool Reform for the Individual Market

  • Establishes Independent Health Pools (IHPs) in order to allow individuals to pool together for the purposes of purchasing insurance.
  • Amends the Public Health Service Act (PHSA) to allow individuals to pool together to provide for health benefits coverage through Individual Health Pools (IHPs). These can include nonprofit organizations (including churches, alumni associations, trade associations, other civic groups, or entities formed strictly for establishing an IHP) so long as the organization does not condition membership on any health status-related factor.

Sure, deregulation is good, but this won’t go anywhere as long as employers provide insurance. Businesses will always have more negotiating power against insurers than self-organized groups of individuals, so people will always get a better deal from their job than their individual group.

Interstate Market for Health Insurance

  • Increases access to individual health coverage by allowing insurers licensed to sell policies in one state to offer them to residents of any other state.
  • Exempts issuers from secondary state laws that would prohibit or regulate their operation in the secondary state. However, states may impose requirements such as consumer protections and applicable taxes, among others.
  • Gives sole jurisdiction to the primary state to enforce the primary state’s covered laws in the primary state and any secondary state.
  • Allows the secondary state to notify the primary state if the coverage offered in the secondary state fails to comply with the covered laws in the primary state.

In addition to HSA’s, this is the other major tent pole of the new Republican health insurance agenda. Trump especially emphasized deregulation of state barriers on insurance as a major fix to the health insurance market. That’s probably not the case. The problem is that insurers trying to move into new states do not have a provider network in the target state, and therefore have no negotiating power which results in plans that are more expensive and networks that are smaller than the incumbent insurers. Even Kaiser ended up fumbling when they tried expanding to the east coast. The idea is good, and the changes are a move in the right direction, but it likely won’t be meaningful except for cases where insurers are especially abusive in their relationship with the local providers.

Association Health Plans

  • Association Health Plans (AHPs) allow small businesses to pool together across state lines through their membership in a trade or professional association to purchase health coverage for their employees and their families. AHPs increase the bargaining power, leverage discounts, and provide administrative efficiencies to small businesses while freeing them from state benefit mandates

More bad policy. We discussed already how employer sponsored health insurance is bad because it limits individual participation in the insurance marketplace and results in suboptimal health insurance utilization. While this change has the understandable goal of increasing small business bargaining power against insurers, it only expands the employer’s presence in the insurance marketplace when we need less of it. In the words of American philosopher Donald Trump, “Bad!”

Anti-Trust Reform for Healthcare

  • Provides an exemption from Federal antitrust laws for health care professionals engaged in negotiations with a health plan regarding the terms of a contract under which the professionals provide health care items or services.
  • This section applies only to health care professionals excluded from the National Labor Relations Act. It would also not apply to contracts or care provided under Medicare, Medicaid, SCHIP, the FEHBP, or the IHS as well as medical and dental care provided to members of the uniformed services and veterans.

Hold on. Full stop. What? So if a health insurance company tries to negotiate a rate with an independent specialist, the Sherman anti-trust act is waived and he is allowed to collude with all the other independent specialists in an area in order to push up his negotiated rates? In an economy where physicians are generally overpaid compared to their counterfactuals? From an economic perspective that’s fine, cartels fall apart because there’s always an incentive for members to cheat and eventually one of the colluders will independently agree to lower rates in exchange for more referrals. But Anti-Trust Reform? Let’s at least be honest Sen. Rand “Physician Special Interest” Paul that this will only increase cost of care and call it Trust Empowerment.

Increasing State Flexibility to Conduct Medicaid Waivers

  • Provides new flexibilities to states in their Medicaid plan design, through existing waiver authority in current law.

The final tent pole in Republican healthcare policy, giving power back to the states, a tale as old as time. This is guaranteed to be part of the final policy, regardless of whose plan is passed. Innovation and decentralization is good and I look forward to what the states will create.

Self-Insurance Protections

  • Amends the definition of “health insurance coverage” under the Public Health Service Act (PHSA), and parallel sections of ERISA and the Tax Code, to clarify that stop-loss insurance is not health insurance.
  • This provision is designed to prevent the federal government from using rule-making to restrict the availability of stop-loss insurance used by self-insured plans.

This is interesting. Some of these regulations are decent, like requiring stop-loss insurance to cover unpaid claims if the small business plan terminates. Others, like requiring a certain amount of healthcare spending before stop-loss is allowed to kick in, are very invasive. That being said, it is completely correct to say that stop-loss insurance is not health insurance. If it were, every single financial product that insurance companies use to manage their risk profile could be construed as health insurance.

Conclusion

What’s the verdict? It’s pretty disappointing. The only good thing it achieves is the repeal itself, because the replacement is mediocre. A mixture of decent changes that aren’t going to reduce costs significantly (interstate sale, individual pool reform) and well-intentioned bad policy (tax treatment equalization, association health plans).

In fact, it’s embarrassing that people claim Sen. Rand Paul is libertarian leaning when this bill engages in such heavy manipulation of the tax code and obvious  pandering to the physician special interest. The biggest problem with the bill is that it focuses entirely on health insurance reform and does nothing with respect to  regulation on the provider side of the equation. Obamacare proved that you can’t reduce health care costs through financial engineering, but even Obamacare tried to address provider behavior with bundled payments and the accountable care organizations. Healthcare COSTS will not be reduced until providers have to quote prices, until incumbents are no longer protected by certificates of need, and until the physician trade union is no longer protected by scope of practice and licensing restrictions.

Failing to push any provider side change(except for empowering their cartel powers!), or provide any evidence based insurance reforms, the bill gets a C+. Why not an F? There’s a fringe case where it could work out. The tax treatment equalization section means that there will be no tax treatment difference between employer sponsored health insurance premiums being paid directly by the employer or by the employee. Therefore some employers may opt to increase employee wages and not pay directly for health insurance in order to appear more competitive in the job market. Healthy employees then could choose to opt out of health insurance and keep the money instead of buying through their employer. This would result in an employer sponsored insurance death spiral due to increasing average costs, which would ultimately increase the uninsured population and could force providers to compete on price. That’s a lot of ifs, however. A simple “providers must quote a real price on their website for every episode of care that they provide” bill is much more reliable.

Rare diseases are the great case for UHC

The Economist’s article reporting on developments in gene therapy for rare diseases mentions something important:

The lessons from Glybera, the first gene therapy to be sold in Europe, still loom large. It cures a genetic condition that causes a dangerously high amount of fat to build up in the blood system. Priced at $1m, the product has only been bought once since 2012 and stands out as a commercial disaster.

Incredibly high need for the patient, but high development costs, essentially non-existent consumer base, no competition, no economies of scale, and no consumer bargaining power. Any one of those can destroy a market, but all at once? The only thing that would make it worse is if the patients can’t pay. Oh, right. They can’t. Because it costs $1m. If I’ve ever heard of a perfect government job, then this is it.

In the US, rare disease treatments will need to be covered by CMS and the associated costs spread across the entire tax base, because the free market will quite literally never be able to find a humane solution for this problem. Good luck using charity, vouchers or tax credits to cover a $1m treatment.

Health Fail – ACA Smoking Surcharges

Sometimes people’s behavior triggers, surprises and pleases me all at once. The ACA contains a provision enabling insurance providers to add a surcharge on the premiums of smokers, hoping to incentivize smokers to quit. Yale researchers report in Health Affairs how the smokers reacted to these incentives:

That’s right. Smokers dropped insurance coverage. I can’t even anymore.

The administration managed to put through a measure penalizing smoking without using the word that shall not be spoken in congress (tax) and got outsmarted (outdumbed?) by the smokers. I napped through most of my college macro economics course, but the one thing I took away from that class was that if you encounter a market failure that you want to correct, you tax it directly and never tangentially.

This is exactly why.

By the way, this is also why we desperately need to #MakeTaxesGreatAgain in U.S. politics. Treating the taxman as a pariah is tying down policymakers hands with foolish and disastrous consequences.